October-December Issue
Dealing With Global Warming:
The Need for Long-Term Actions
n
recent years, intense international negotiations have focused on how much
each of the developed nations should limit their emissions of carbon dioxide
(CO2). Now researchers in MIT's Joint Program
on the Science and Policy of Global Change warn that setting such limits
will not by itself be a sufficient response if the threat of global warming
proves real. Analyses using their "Integrated Global System Model"
suggest that even the toughest current proposal for limiting emissions
from developed nations will reduce projected warming in 2100 by only about
20%. Further, the analyses show that developed countries alone cannot reduce
emissions enough to stabilize atmospheric CO2
concentrations at levels now proposed as "safe." The rapidly
growing emissions from developing nations must also be curbed. There are
even more challenging tasks for the long-term future. First, we should
develop "greenhouse-friendly" technologies that permit emissions
reductions without threatening economic health. Second, we should design
broad international climate agreements that can evolve over time and that
address all issues, from sources and sinks of all greenhouse gases to emissions
monitoring and enforcement. Finally, we should develop an international
system that can, if necessary, transfer substantial funds to developing
countries to support their emissions-control efforts. These long-term undertakings
should be tackled with the same fervor that characterizes current negotiations
on near-term emissions limits.
The signing of the Berlin Mandate in 1995 initiated intense
international negotiations to develop a response to potential climate change.
Under the mandate, diplomats were instructed to devise a set of national
ceilings for greenhouse gas emissions for the early years of the next century.
To make agreement more likely, developing countries were not to be asked
to control emissions, although they account for roughly half the greenhouse
emissions now and will emit a larger share in coming decades. The near-term
focus is on emissions of carbon dioxide (CO2),
recognized as the most important human contributor to potential global
warming. Results of the negotiations were the focus of the international
conference on climate change that was held in Kyoto, Japan, in December
1997.
As a result of the Berlin Mandate, climate change debate during the past
two years has focused on a single question: how much will each of the developed
nations promise to cut CO2 emissions by
2010? Preoccupation with that question worries researchers in the MIT Joint
Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change. Achieving near-term
limits on CO2 emissions is important, agree
Professors Henry D. Jacoby, Ronald G. Prinn, and Richard L. Schmalensee.
But negotiations toward that goal may be counterproductive if they delay
actions necessary to mount and sustain a broader and longer-term global
effort to deal with the threat of potential climate change.
The researchers' concern arises in part from their ongoing investigations
into uncertainties that plague predictions of human influences on climate.
Experts agree that concentrations of CO2
and other greenhouse gases in the atmosphere have increased substantially
over the past century and that the presence of those gases will tend to
trap the sun's infrared energy, raising temperatures at the Earth's surface.
But other aspects are controversial. The impact of changes in temperature
on our climate depends on complicated, interacting phenomena in the atmosphere,
the oceans, and land ecosystems, all of which are poorly understood. Long-term
emissions of greenhouse gases are themselves highly uncertain because they
depend on economic, technological, and political forces that are hard to
predict. And least of all is known about how changes in climate may affect
people, society, and natural systems.
To help analyze and quantify the uncertainty associated with climate forecasts,
a group of MIT scientists and economists including Professors Jacoby, Prinn,
and Schmalensee have formulated a computer model that couples global economic
development, climate processes, and ecosystem behavior. Unlike other models
in this field, the Integrated Global System Model (IGSM) combines detailed
treatments of the relevant natural and economic processes (see e-lab, January-March
1997). Using the model, the researchers have explored the consequences
of a range of "reasonable" assumptions about future economic
development and fundamental climate processes. Their results provide guidance
for both policymaking and future research directions.
One important conclusion is that the range of plausible outcomes is enormous.
The figure below shows how using various sets of assumptions about future
human activities and about natural processes affects predictions of the
change in global average surface temperature between 1990 and 2100. (The
predictions assume that future greenhouse gas emissions are not restricted
by regulation.) The assumptions are all reasonable, but they produce widely
varying results. For example, using the most optimistic assumptions, the
predicted increase in temperature by the year 2100 is only 2 degrees F. However,
using the "worst-case" assumptions, the predicted increase is
fully 9 degrees F. Two thirds of the difference in those predictions is due
to uncertainty about climate processes; the other third reflects uncertainty
about emissions. The lowest predicted pathway in the figure would probably
do little harm, but the highest predicted pathway would almost certainly
threaten important natural processes as well as agriculture and other human
activities.
Clearly, scientists must continue research to improve
emissions forecasts, climate models, and impact estimates. In addition,
they must continue to watch for evidence that human activities are indeed
influencing climate. Many scientists now believe that it may be a decade
or more before human effects can be discerned from natural variations in
climate. Nevertheless, continued vigilance is critical, as demonstrated
in the figure. The shaded region at the bottom represents an estimate of
how much global mean temperatures vary naturally during the course of a
century. An increase in actual temperatures greater than that natural variability
provides evidence that human activities are affecting climate. Looking
at the various forecasts, it is clear that the sooner the observed temperatures
rise above that range of natural variability, the greater the eventual
predicted warming, and the more important it will be to take quick and
dramatic action to forestall large climate impacts.
If global warming does turn out to be a problem, IGSM analyses suggest
that the emissions reductions agreed to at the Kyoto meeting will not--by
themselves--do much to solve it. The researchers considered one of the
toughest proposals that was considered at Kyoto: the call by the European
Union (EU) to reduce CO2 emissions from
"Annex I" countries to 15% below 1990 levels by 2010--fully 9%
more than in the final agreement. (Annex I countries are those subject
to emissions limits, namely the members of the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development as of 1990, plus Eastern Europe and most of
the former Soviet Union.) Achieving such a large reduction in CO2
emissions in little more than a decade would be expensive, and maintaining
the proposed 2010 level of emissions for the rest of the century would
be even more difficult. Yet even under the assumptions of the mid-range
MIT forecast in the first figure, IGSM analyses show that this effort by
Annex I countries would reduce the projected warming in 2100 by only about
20%, largely because of projected emissions growth in developing countries--growth
that is not restricted by the Kyoto agreement. If climate change turns
out to be a serious threat, this response would be inadequate; if it turns
out not to be a threat, it would be a large-scale waste of resources.
A longer-term goal involves stabilizing atmospheric concentrations of greenhouse
gases. The EU and others have recommended stabilizing concentrations of
CO2 at 550 ppm (roughly twice pre-industrial
levels), and the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has outlined
an emissions-reduction strategy for achieving that goal. Based on an IGSM
analysis, the MIT researchers predict that following that strategy would
lower the mid-range warming forecast by only about 30% in 2100. Moreover,
the Annex I nations could not accomplish the called-for emissions reductions
by themselves. The figure below shows the maximum Annex I emissions consistent
with the EU's proposed target (based on assumptions corresponding to the
mid-range of the forecasts in the figure above). The non-Annex I nations
are assumed to continue emitting CO2 without
restriction, and their forecasted emissions are simply subtracted from
the global total that the EU proposal allows, as calculated by the IPCC.
Without participation by the developing world, following the proposed emissions-reduction
strategy would require that emissions by the Annex I nations somehow become
negative around the middle of the next century!
One conclusion seems clear: unless scientists discover
soon that greenhouse warming is definitely not a threat, the struggle to
devise a global response will occupy not just our generation but future
generations as well. The MIT researchers identify three actions that should
be taken now to help future generations cope. The first is to develop better
technical options that could, if necessary, permit us to control greenhouse
gas emissions while maintaining economic growth. A serious attempt to produce
important new technological options would be cheap relative to the cost
of controlling emissions resulting from the use of current technologies.
The best route to achieving such advances is not clear. Marketplace incentives
appear important for stimulating private sector R&D, while public expenditure
may be needed on basic research and fundamental technologies. The latter
will require a major turnabout of today's minimal commitment to developing
greenhouse-friendly technology.
The second action is to begin developing institutions and policies that
allow us to mount and sustain a very long term global effort to control
climate change. We need to establish an institutional structure for managing
global emissions agreements that can evolve easily over time. Useful insights
can be gained from the international trade regime developed under the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), now the World Trade Organization.
This organization has grown and evolved over time, adding countries and
goods along the way, peacefully resolving substantial conflicts in national
economic interests, and contributing to global economic growth. (Unfortunately,
achieving that success required fifty years of hard work.) In addition,
policies limiting CO2 emissions should
be just one part of a larger, carefully designed set of international agreements
that address all the issues involved. For example, agreements must cover
not just CO2 produced from fossil fuels
but also all the important sources and sinks of significant greenhouse
gases. They also need to provide for reliable emissions monitoring and
for some system of sanctions for those who violate their obligations.
The third area that warrants attention concerns the inclusion of non-Annex
I nations. Making significant reductions in global emissions will require
global participation. Therefore, Annex I targets and timetables must be
designed to facilitate the inclusion of non-Annex I nations. In many cases,
these nations will not be able to afford voluntary abatement much before
the end of the next century. Thus, if the rich countries want to stabilize
greenhouse gas concentrations, they must not only control their own emissions
but also pay poor countries to reduce their emissions. Rough estimates
of the costs that would be involved imply international transfers of wealth
on a scale well beyond anything in recorded history. We need to create
an international system that can transfer substantial sums to developing
countries to support their participation in an emissions-control effort.
Including the developing countries in that effort will affect another important
financial factor: the global cost of controlling emissions. Many of the
cheapest emissions-abatement opportunities are in developing countries,
and exploiting those opportunities first would minimize the global cost
of achieving a given reduction in emissions. To take advantage of those
opportunities, some observers have proposed establishing a system of emissions
trading--the approach that has dramatically reduced sulfur dioxide pollution
in the United States (see e-lab, January-March 1997). Emissions trading
is not included in the Kyoto agreement. But even if it is adopted in later
agreements, it will work effectively only if all countries have agreed
to emissions limits. If the developing countries do not participate, the
advantages of trading are drastically reduced.
Henry D. Jacoby and Ronald G. Prinn are co-directors of the MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change. Professor Jacoby is William F. Pounds Professor of Management. Professor Prinn is TEPCO Professor of Atmospheric Chemistry and director of the Center for Global Change Science. Richard L. Schmalensee is Gordon Y Billard Professor of Management and Economics, director of the MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, and associate dean of the MIT Sloan School of Management. This research was supported by a government-industry partnership including the US Department of Energy, the National Science Foundation, the US National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, the US Environmental Protection Agency, the Royal Norwegian Ministries of Energy and Industry and Foreign Affairs, and a group of corporate sponsors from the United States, Europe, and Japan. Further information can be found in the references.